Corruption and Fraud Videos at this blog site:
http://northshorelive.blogspot.com/
Editor's note: Your ProbateShark prays that "Law Enforcement" at all levels will view the Stratos Pahis document and conclude that the crimnal judges of the Probate Court of Cook County fit into its framework. Lucius Verenus, Schoolmaster, ProbateSharks.com
Corruption in Our Courts: What It Looks Like and Where It Is Hidden, Stratos Pahis
abstract. Recent surveys and events indicate that judicial corruption could be a significant
problem in the United States. This Note builds an economic model of bribery to better
understand the incentives behind this pernicious phenomenon. It then compiles a data set of
discovered incidents of judicial bribery in the United States to test the effectiveness of our antijudicial-
corruption institutions. This analysis suggests that our institutions are particularly
ineffective at preventing and uncovering judicial bribery in civil disputes and traffic hearings.
author. Yale Law School, J.D. 2009; Universidad Complutense de Madrid, M.A. 2005;
Dartmouth College, B.A. 2004. I am grateful to Professor Susan Rose-Ackerman for inspiring
my interest in this topic and for her invaluable support and feedback over many drafts of this
Note. I am also indebted to the members of The Yale Law Journal Notes Committee—in
particular to Victoria Weatherford for her patience, meticulous editing, and insightful
comments. Thanks also to Sam Ferguson for his helpful feedback. All errors that remain are of
course mine alone.
corruption in our courts
1903
“If experience demands a presumption that a judge will seize every
opportunity presented to him in the course of his official conduct to line his
pockets, no canon of ethics or statute regarding disqualification can save our
judicial system.”
—Justice William Rehnquist1
introduction
A judiciary without honesty has little chance of executing its moral and
constitutional duties, no matter how many rules of ethics exist. This is
especially true in the United States, where the judiciary is afforded wide
discretion. Facts and law require interpretation; justice and equity require
judgment. Every decision to grant a motion, to follow precedent, to interpret a
statute or facts, to set a sentence or damages—every decision left up to the
discretion of a judge—is a potential opportunity for corruption. Eliminating all
opportunities for personal gain would require nothing less than the destruction
of the independent and adaptable judicial system we know. And so we count
on honest judges to navigate our ship of justice through these dangerous
waters.
But we do not just keep our fingers crossed and hope we have good
captains at the helm. We develop processes of choosing the most skilled and
honest judges. We provide them with good pay and professional prestige to
lessen the temptations of bribery. And we develop multilevel methods of
oversight that intrude minimally (one hopes) upon their discretion and
independence. We expect judges to be honest because we establish institutions
that incentivize honesty.
Despite the critical importance of maintaining judicial integrity, there is a
dearth of empirical literature that analyzes the effectiveness of these
institutions. To be sure, some studies have tracked the historical development
of judicial integrity institutions and others have catalogued cases of judicial
corruption.2 Others still have relied upon questionnaires to gauge perceptions
1904
and incidences of corruption.3 But because no study has ventured beyond the
description of discovered cases of judicial corruption, none has been able to
answer the question of how effective our institutions have been at actually
unearthing and punishing the crime.4
This Note begins to fill in this serious gap in the literature on judicial
corruption. By developing an economic model to understand judicial
corruption and creating the only recent sample of discovered cases of judicial
bribery against which to test its predictions, this Note attempts to assess the
effectiveness of our anticorruption mechanisms. In doing so, beyond
cataloguing important patterns in judicial corruption, it advances the argument
that there is a serious blind spot in the functioning of our anticorruption
institutions. While the small sample size limits the certainty of this Note’s
findings, its analysis suggests that the mechanisms for detecting bribery of
judges in civil matters and traffic violations are deficient and that much judicial
corruption in these cases likely goes unnoticed.
Before moving on, it is worth mentioning why I have specifically focused
this Note on judicial bribery. After all, many forms of judicial corruption exist
and may in fact be more widespread than quid pro quo bribery. Cases of judges
ruling on matters involving a financial or personal conflict of interest are
numerous and are responsible for a large portion of sanctions handed down by
state judicial conduct organizations (JCOs).5 The receiving of gifts, the
granting of favors, ex parte communications, and other actions that create
partiality or its appearance are also highly prevalent forms of malfeasance dealt
with by JCOs.
Despite the importance of these forms of corruption, I have chosen to limit
my study to bribery cases for three reasons. First, a recent survey suggests that
judicial bribery may be a significant problem in the United States. In a
Transparency International survey, 2% of the North Americans (defined to
include residents of the United States and Canada) who had come into contact
judicial corruption); Geoffrey P. Miller, Bad Judges, 83 TEX. L. REV. 431 (2004) (cataloguing
cases of judicial malfeasance).
with the judiciary over the previous year reported having paid bribes.6
Assuming parity of corruption between the United States and Canada,7 and a
U.S. adult population of 220 million,8 this study implies that over one million
bribes are paid in the U.S. judicial system each year. While this survey captures
bribes directed not only toward judges, but also toward police, prosecutors,
and jurors, the results are alarming enough to warrant further study into
judges, whose integrity is most critical to a functioning judicial system.
Second, cases of bribery offer greater details for study than do other forms of
corruption. Because bribery is prosecutable, incidents of it should be relatively
well investigated and reported. Third, bribery is one of the most pernicious
forms of corruption. It can purchase favors in high-stakes cases and does not
necessitate any personal or professional relationship between the briber and
judge. It would seem, therefore, to be one of the most serious—and difficult to
detect—forms of judicial corruption that exists. The most recent judicial
scandal to come out of Pennsylvania, in which two judges pled guilty to
accepting bribes from a private juvenile detention facility in exchange for
incarcerating minors for extended periods of time, is evidence of just how vile
and pernicious the consequences of judicial bribery can be. During the last five
years, the judges collected over $2.6 million in bribes and presided over the
trials of five thousand children, including one teenager who was sentenced to
five months detention for stealing DVDs from Walmart.9
This Note is organized as follows: In Part I, I develop an economic model
for understanding judicial bribery. In Part II, I review the accountability
institutions of the state and federal judiciaries and describe the sample set of
corrupt judges. I then go over the characteristics of the judges and courts in
which bribery was discovered in Part III. In Part IV, I discuss the types of
bribery discovered, the prices of the bribes and the corrupt actions that they
bought, how the judges and bribers transacted the bribes, and what factors led
to the bribes’ discovery. This analysis leads to the troubling observation that
that some were corrupted by as little as a pound of lunch meat.
In Part V, I examine interesting patterns from the data—in particular, the
disproportionate amount of discovered bribery in criminal cases as compared
to bribery in civil cases. I observe that this discrepancy appears to be due in
large part to prosecutorial leverage, which allows criminals to bargain down
their sentence in return for incriminating information about judges, leading to
an increased rate of detection. After examining other possible explanations for
the discrepancy, I argue that the data and model support the conclusion that
bribery in civil cases is less likely to be detected than bribery in criminal cases. I
conclude with a summary of my findings and suggestions for further research.
i . understanding and observing judicial corruption
The study of corruption poses unique problems. Corruption’s covert nature
means that only a fraction of it is ever exposed. Those cases that are discovered
almost certainly share characteristics that led to their discovery. Relying solely
on discovered cases of corruption as a means of analysis is therefore a limited
method that can provide a distorted view of how much and what kind of
corruption actually exists. This limitation has led scholars to rely on survey
data of public perceptions of corruption as a proxy for the amount of
corruption that exists.10 The accuracy or inaccuracy of such perceptions
notwithstanding, relying solely on public perceptions of corruption is bound to
constrain the specificity of the conclusions. This Part provides another
framework for understanding judicial corruption.
A. An Economic Model of Bribery
Judicial corruption can be understood as the selling and purchasing of legal
decisions. Understanding judicial bribery requires understanding the
incentives that exist for parties or lawyers to purchase these decisions and for
judges to sell them.11 Below, in an attempt to predict what types of cases and
This Article is continued at the link below:
http://impeachrandykennedy.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Thank you for commenting.
Your comment will be held for approval by the blog owner.